Read the Beforeitsnews.com story here. Advertise at Before It's News here.
Profile image
By Steve Keen's Debtwatch (Reporter)
Contributor profile | More stories
Story Views
Now:
Last hour:
Last 24 hours:
Total:

Modeling Financial Instability

% of readers think this story is Fact. Add your two cents.


This paper will be published in a forthcoming book on the crisis edited by Malliaris, Shaw and Shefrin. In what follows, I derive a corrected formula for the role of the change in debt in aggregate demand, which is that ex-post aggregate demand equals ex-ante income plus the circulation of new debt, where the latter term is the velocity of money times the ex-post creation of new debt.

The PDF is available here: Keen2014ModelingFinancialInstability. The Minsky models used in this paper are here in a ZIP file. The latest version of Minsky can be downloaded from here.

  • Introduction

Literally no-one disputes that the financial sector was the cause of the post-2007 economic crisis: disputation instead centers on the causal mechanisms. I follow Fisher (Fisher 1933) and Minsky (Minsky 1980) in assigning key roles to the growth and contraction of aggregate private debt (Keen 1995; Keen 2000), but this perspective is rejected by New Keynesian economists on the a priori basis that private debts are “pure redistributions” that “should have no significant macro-economic effects” (Bernanke 2000p. 24), and as a corollary to the oft-repeated truism that “one person’s debt is another person’s asset” (Krugman 2012c, p. 43).

My analysis also follows the Post Keynesian tradition of endogenous money (Moore 1979; Moore 1983) in seeing the banking sector as an essential component of the macroeconomy, yet this is also dismissed by New Keynesian economists on the grounds that banks are merely a specialized form of financial intermediary (Krugman 2012a; Krugman 2012b; Krugman 2013a; Sumner 2013; Tobin 1963), all of which can be safely ignored in macroeconomic models. When banks are introduced in New Keynesian models, they function not as loan originators but effectively as brokers between savers and borrowers (Eggertsson and Krugman 2012b, pp. 21–22).

In response, authors in the Post Keynesian and Endogenous Money traditions express exasperation that New Keynesian authors ignore credit creation and the accounting mechanics of bank lending (Fullwiler 2012; Roche 2013), as laid out in numerous Central Bank publications (Carpenter and Demiralp 2010; ECB 2012; Holmes 1969; Keister and McAndrews 2009).

Given the key public policy role of economics, and the acknowledged failure of Neoclassical models in general to anticipate the financial crisis (Bezemer 2009; Blanchard 2009; Blanchard, et al. 2010; OECD 2007), the existence within academic economics of two diametrically opposed perspectives which fail to communicate is a disservice to the public.

In this paper I attempt to conclusively determine whether aggregate private debt and banks matter in macroeconomics by putting the two rival models of lending—Loanable Funds and Endogenous Money—on a common footing. Using the dynamic Open Source monetary modeling program Minsky, I firstly put the New Keynesian model of banking in Eggertsson & Krugman 2012b into a strictly monetary model and I show that, if the structure of lending in this model accurately characterizes actual lending, then the Neoclassical perspective that aggregate debt is unimportant, and that banks can safely be ignored in macroeconomics, is correct. I then modify this model to match the Post Keynesian perspective on the structure of lending, and show that in this structure, changes in the aggregate level of private debt have a direct impact upon aggregate demand, and banks therefore play a crucial role in macroeconomics.

  1. Loanable Funds vs Endogenous Money

The Neoclassical model of “Loanable Funds” and the Post Keynesian concept of “Endogenous Money” constitute the polar opposites on the nature and significance of banks, debt and money in macroeconomics. Both models portray the money supply as variable, and hence in one sense endogenous, though by very different mechanisms and to very different degrees (Palley 2013, p. 411). In the Loanable Funds tradition, banks function as “mere intermediaries” (Graziani 1989, p. 8) between savers and borrowers, private debts are “pure redistributions” that “should have no significant macro-economic effects” (Bernanke 2000, p. 24), and banks, debt and money can be and are ignored in canonical macroeconomic models (Smets and Wouters 2007; Woodford 2009). In the Endogenous Money tradition, banks are crucial to macroeconomics because they create money by creating debt (Holmes 1969; Moore 1979), but no consensus has yet emerged on how to represent this phenomenon in Post Keynesian macroeconomic models (Palley 1991; Palley 2002).

There is little communication between the two approaches, with authors in the Loanable Funds tradition frequently deriding those in the Endogenous Money camp (Krugman 2012a; Krugman 2012b; Krugman 2012e; Krugman 2012f), and dismissing the proposition that banks must be included in macroeconomics (Krugman 2012a; Krugman 2012b; Krugman 2012d; but see Rowe 2013; Sumner 2013).

This dispute can be resolved by an appeal to the Occam’s Razor principle that unless a more complex model makes different and better predictions than a less complex one, the simpler should be preferred. Therefore, unless bank lending necessarily affects vital macroeconomic aggregates in a significant manner, then even though the “loans create deposits” accounting perspective of Endogenous Money is technically correct (Carney 2012; ECB 2012; Holmes 1969)—as even Paul Krugman has conceded (Krugman 2013a)— the Loanable Funds approach is justified, and banks should be excluded from macroeconomics. Conversely, if bank lending necessarily affects macroeconomic aggregates, then banks, debt and the endogeneity of the money supply are integral to macroeconomics, and models that exclude them are not models of a capitalist economy.

  1. A monetary model of Loanable Funds

Eggertsson and Krugman note that the vast majority of mainstream economic models ignore debt:

If there is a single word that appears most frequently in discussions of the economic problems now afflicting both the United States and Europe, that word is surely debt… one might have expected debt to be at the heart of most mainstream macroeconomic models—especially the analysis of monetary and fiscal policy. Perhaps somewhat surprisingly, however, it is quite common to abstract altogether from this feature of the economy. Even economists trying to analyze the problems of monetary and fiscal policy at the zero lower bound—and yes, that includes the present authors (see Krugman 1998, Eggertsson and Woodford 2003)—have often adopted representative agent models in which everyone is alike and the shock that pushes the economy into a situation in which even a zero interest rate is not low enough takes the form of a shift in everyone’s preferences. (Eggertsson and Krugman 2012a, pp. 1469–71)

In order to introduce debt into a New Keynesian two-period model, Eggertsson and Krugman divided agents into two groups who “differ only in their rates of time preference”: “patient agents” and “impatient agents” where the latter have a higher rate of time preference than the former, so that “In that case, ”impatient” individuals will borrow from ”patient” individuals.” (Eggertsson and Krugman 2012ap. 1474). Debt was explicitly modeled throughout this paper, and banking was introduced in the Appendix (Eggertsson and Krugman 2012b) as an intermediating function between depositors and borrowers, where borrowing by impatient agents was strictly for investment.

The authors describe their model as a “just the standard New Keynesian model”, with one twist, in that the natural rate of interest, which is normally an exogenous parameter in the IS equation, is instead endogenous with borrowers’ debt being one of its parameters. Therefore the level of private debt plays a macroeconomic role:

we need to figure out the evolution of debt of the “borrowers” to figure out the natural rate of interest. In particular we see that if … the economy is “overleveraged” … it is easy to get endogenously negative natural rate of interest. (Eggertsson and Krugman 2012b, p. 24)

The New Keynesian and “Liquidity Trap” aspects of this model (on which see Solow 2003; Solow 2008) are tangential to the topic of this paper, which is a strictly structural one: does bank lending—as opposed to lending by non-bank agents to each other—significantly alter the macrodynamics of the economy? To consider this question, I render the Loanable Funds aspects of Eggertsson and Krugman 2012b in a strictly monetary form in a Minsky model.

Minsky is a system dynamics program which generates dynamic models of financial flows from double-entry bookkeeping tables (called “Godley Tables” in the program), in which the columns represent bank accounts and the rows are transactions between accounts. The sample model shown in Figure 1 generates the dynamic equations shown in Equation (more details on Minsky are given in the Appendix).

Figure 1: Sample Godley Table and banking icon in Minsky

The Loanable Funds features of Eggertsson and Krugman (2012b) are:

  • that deposits by the “patient agents” enable loans to “impatient agents”; and
  • that banks intermediate between saver and borrower and profit by an intermediation fee, but otherwise play no role in lending.

The Minsky model shown in Figure 2 replicates these features using the bank accounts of four separate entities: the consumption goods sector (with deposit account DepCons) which is the lender in (Eggertsson and Krugman 2012b); the investment goods sector (with account DepInv) which is the borrower; Workers (with account Workers) who are employed by both the Consumption Sector and the Investment Sector; and
the Banking sector (with the Asset account Reserves and equity account BankersNW) which intermediates the loans from
the Consumption Sector to the Investment Sector, and charges a fee for doing so. Each sector maintains a financial table showing the flows into and out of its accounts, and calculates its net worth as a result as the difference between the value of its assets and liabilities (account BankersNW for the banking sector).

Figure 2: Loanable Funds model—a 4 account view of Loanable Funds generated in Minsky

Table 1 shows this financial system from the banking sector’s perspective, and Table 2 shows it from the perspective of the lender, the Consumption Sector. Following the conventions in Minsky, assets are shown as positive amounts, and liabilities and equity are shown as negatives, while the source of any financial transaction is shown as a positive and its destination as a negative. All entries in the table represent flows, and Minsky automatically generates the resulting system of differential equations in LaTeX. The ten flows that define the model are all shown in the banking sector’s table, and are respectively:

  1. The Consumption Sector lends to the Investment Sector via the flow “Lend” from the account DepCons to the account DepInv;
  2. The Investment sector makes Interest payments “Int” to the consumption sector;
  3. The Banking Sector charges the Consumption Sector an intermediation fee “IntFee”;
  4. The investment Sector makes debt repayments to the Consumption Sector (“Repay”);
  5. The Consumption Sector hires Workers via the flow “WagesC”;
  6. The investment Sector hires Workers via the flow “WagesI”;
  7. The Investment Sector purchases consumption goods (“ConsI”);
  8. The Consumption Sector purchases investment goods (“ConsC”);
  9. Workers purchase consumer goods (“ConsW”); and
  10. Bankers purchase consumer goods (“ConsB”);

Table 1: Loanable Funds model from the Banking Sector’s perspective

Banking Sector

Assets

Liabilities

Equity

Flows Accounts Reserves DepCons DepInv Workers BankersNW
1 Lending Lend –Lend
2 Interest Payments –Int Int
3 Bank Intermediation Fee IntFee –IntFee
4 Debt Repayment –Repay Repay
5 Hire workers (Cons) WagesC –WagesC
6 Hire workers (Inv) WagesI –WagesI
7 Intersectoral purchases by Inv –ConsI ConsI
8 Intersectoral purchases by Cons ConsC –ConsC
9 Workers consumption –ConsW ConsW
10 Bankers consumption –ConsB ConsB

 

Lending from the consumption to the investment sector is recorded in the account Loans, which is an asset of the consumption sector as shown in its financial account (see Table 2; it also appears as a liability of the Investment Sector in its table of accounts; Table 2 also displays the dynamics of the Consumption Sector’s net worth in the column “ConsNW”).

Table 2: Loanable Funds model from the Consumption Sector’s perspective

Consumption Sector Assets Equity
Flows Accounts DepCons Loans ConsNW
1 Lending –Lend Lend
2 Interest Payments Int –Int
3 Bank Intermediation Fee –IntFee IntFee
4 Debt Repayment Repay –Repay
5 Hire workers (Cons) –WagesC WagesC
6 Intersectoral purchases by Inv ConsI –ConsI
7 Intersectoral purchases by Cons –ConsC ConsC
8 Workers consumption ConsW –ConsW
9 Bankers consumption ConsB –ConsB

 

Since (for the sake of simplicity) holdings of cash are ignored in this model, money is the sum of the amounts in the four deposit accounts DepCons, DepInv, Workers, and BankersNW shown in Table 1, while debt is the amount in the account Loans shown in Table 2. Equation shows the equations for the dynamics of money and debt in the model, with the first 4 equations derived from Table 1 showing the dynamics of money in the system while the final equation, derived from Table 2, shows the dynamics of debt.

Defining money M as the sum of the first four accounts, it is obvious that the change in the amount of money is zero:

Therefore the amount of money—which for convenience we can treat this as having been created by government fiat, without needing to specify a government sector in the model—remains constant:

Without having to define a full economic model, we can now specify aggregate demand AD as being equivalent to the turnover of the money in the economy, using the velocity of money v (see Figure 3 and Equation ).

Figure 3: Velocity of M2 money stock in the USA 1960–2013

As is well known, contrary to Milton Friedman’s claims (Friedman 1948; Friedman 1959; Friedman 1969; Friedman and Schwartz 1963), the velocity of money is not a constant—“it is also apparent that money velocities are procyclical and quite volatile” (Kydland and Prescott 1990, p. 14). However the identity that can be used in this simple model to map from the money stock to the level of aggregate demand.

Using the subscript LM to indicate that this is aggregate demand in a Loanable Funds model, we have that aggregate demand at time t is the velocity of money times the stock of money at that time:

Aggregate demand across any defined time period t2–t1 will therefore be this instantaneous flow times the time period itself:

Finally, using D for brevity in place of Loans in Equation , it is obvious that there is no link between the dynamics of debt and either the stock or the turnover of money, and therefore there is no direct relation between private debt and aggregate demand. The amount of money in circulation remains constant:

Given the absence of a relationship between lending and the money supply, the amount of debt in existence can rise or fall substantially with only a minor impact on macroeconomic activity via related changes in the velocity of money:

  1. A monetary model of Endogenous Money

This structural model of Loanable Funds shown in Figure 2 is converted into a model of Endogenous Money by three simple changes:

  • Loans are shifted from the assets of the consumption sector to the assets of the banking sector;
  • Interest payments are transferred to the equity account of the banking sector, BankersNW; and
  • Since banks are loan originators in this model and receive interest payments, the intermediation fee is deleted.

This revised model is shown in Figure 4 and Table 3. The changes between the Loanable Funds model in Table 1 and the Endogenous Money model of Table 3 all occur in the first four rows, with the row for an intermediation fee deleted, and locations of the flows Lend, Int and Repay altered as indicated by the arrows. The two tables are otherwise identical.

Figure 4: Endogenous Money model in Minsky

Table 3: Endogenous Money model from the banking sector’s perspective

Banking Sector

Assets

Liabilities

Equity

Flows Accounts Reserves Loans DepCons DepInv Workers BankersNW
1 Lending Lend   –Lend
2 Interest Payments –> Int –Int
3 Debt Repayment –Repay Repay
4 Hire workers (Cons) WagesC –WagesC
5 Hire workers (Inv) WagesI –WagesI
6 Intersectoral purchases by Inv –ConsI ConsI
7 Intersectoral purchases by Cons ConsC –ConsC
8 Workers consumption –ConsW ConsW
9 Bankers consumption –ConsB ConsB

 

The money and debt equations of this model are:

Despite the simplicity of the changes needed to move from Loanable Funds to Endogenous Money, the dynamics of money are now profoundly different. The rate of change of money is precisely equal to the rate of change of debt:

The stock of money in the economy is therefore the sum of the initial level of money in existence, plus the new money created by the extension of new loans from the banking sector to the investment sector. Assuming for convenience that D(0)=0, this yields:

Using the subscript EM to indicate that this is an Endogenous Money model, aggregate demand is therefore

Aggregate demand during some given time period t2–t1 is therefore:

We can now compare the symbolic measure of nominal aggregate demand in an Endogenous Money model with its counterpart in a Loanable Funds model (the numerical values of velocity, demand and debt will clearly differ substantially, as the simulations in Section 6 illustrate) to identify the substantive difference between a Loanable Funds view of the monetary system and that of Endogenous Money:

The Loanable Funds model thus omits the contribution of the change in debt to the level of aggregate demand.

  1. Occam’s Razor passes Endogenous Money & fails Loanable Funds

If banks make loans to non-banks—as is manifestly the case—and create money in doing so by crediting the deposit accounts of their borrowers—as even the staunch advocate of Loanable Funds Paul Krugman has conceded—then the Loanable Funds model is too extreme a simplification of the nature of capitalism. As Einstein put it in relation to physics:

It can scarcely be denied that the supreme goal of all theory is to make the irreducible basic elements as simple and as few as possible without having to surrender the adequate representation of a single datum of experience. (Einstein 1934, p. 165, emphasis added)

Omitting the capacity of banks to create money, and the impact this has on key macroeconomic aggregates omits a vital “datum of experience” from macroeconomic models. The capacity of bank lending to alter the level of aggregate demand means that banks, debt and money must be included in any adequate model of macroeconomics.

In particular, the acknowledgement of the macroeconomic significance of Endogenous Money requires a dynamic redefinition of aggregate demand to include the change in debt. Though this model excludes second-order effects such as demand for idle cash balances (Rowe 2013), the generic formula relating aggregate demand (AD) to income (Y) and the change of debt is:

This formula corrects a rule of thumb proposition that I have previously asserted, that aggregate demand is the sum of income plus the change in debt (Keen 2014; see also Krugman 2013b). The correct proposition is that, in a world in which the banking sector endogenously creates new money by creating new loans, aggregate demand in a given period is the sum of aggregate demand at the beginning of that period, plus the change in debt over the period multiplied by the velocity of money.

If we consider a time period of one year so that and , and specifying the average velocity of money over that year as v(1) and the change in debt as DD(1), we have

Equations and enable us to operationalize Keynes’s distinction between ex-ante and ex-post, while proving the consistency of this dynamic formula with the standard macroeconomic accounting identity that expenditure equals income. In words, these equations assert that ex-post expenditure equals ex-ante expenditure (and hence income), plus the velocity of money multiplied by the ex-post change in debt.

Since the velocity of money comfortably exceeds unity (though it is highly variable and pro-cyclical), the numerical impact of the change in debt on aggregate demand is therefore larger than I have claimed in research prior to developing this formal proof (Keen 2014; see also Rowe 2013).

  1. Simulating Loanable Funds and Endogenous Money

A simulation of the two models confirms the importance of including the change in debt in aggregate demand. The simple models used here are identical except for the structure of lending, so that the differences in their behavior reflects simply that issue. The models use simple variable time parameters to relate the various monetary flows to each other and the monetary stocks, so that the results do not depend on any behavioral assumptions (see the Appendix for the model equations and default parameter values). The values of two of these parameters—the lending and repayment rates—are varied over the simulations shown in Figure 5 and Figure 6.

Figure 5: Loanable Funds simulation in Minsky

Figure 6: Endogenous Money simulation in Minsky

Variations in the lending and repayment rates have a minor effect on income in the Loanable Funds model (see Figure 7) because they impact upon the velocity of circulation of money (see Figure 8). However the level does not rise (or fall) significantly, and there is no trend, since variations in the level of debt have no impact upon the money supply, which remains constant (see Figure 9).

Figure 7: GDP as a function of Lending & Repayment rates in Loanable Funds

Figure 8: Money velocity as a function of Lending & Repayment rates in Loanable Funds

Figure 9: Money and Debt as functions of Lending & Repayment rates in Loanable Funds

In contrast, variations in the lending and repayment rates have a dramatic impact upon GDP in the Endogenous Money model (see Figure 10), because as well as having an impact upon the velocity of money (see Figure 11) they alter the rate of creation and destruction of money (see Figure 12).

Figure 10: GDP as a function of Lending & Repayment rates in Endogenous Money

Figure 11: Money velocity as a function of Lending & Repayment rates in Endogenous Money

Figure 12: Money and Debt as functions of Lending & Repayment rates in Endogenous Money

  1. Modeling financial instability

The preceding proof provides a theoretical justification for the key role given to the level and change in aggregate private debt in Minsky’s Financial Instability Hypothesis. Empirical research by Fama and French provided further support, by concluding that the correlations they found (including a 0.79 correlation between aggregate corporate investment and change in long term corporate debt) “confirm the impression that debt plays a key role in accommodating year-by-year variation in investment” (Fama and French 1999, p. 1954).

Minsky provided a succinct summary of his Financial Instability Hypothesis, which emphasized the central of private debt to his analysis (Minsky 1978; reprinted in Minsky 1982):

The natural starting place for analyzing the relation between debt and income is to take an economy with a cyclical past that is now doing well. The inherited debt reflects the history of the economy, which includes a period in the not too distant past in which the economy did not do well. Acceptable liability structures are based upon some margin of safety so that expected cash flows, even in periods when the economy is not doing well, will cover contractual debt payments. As the period over which the economy does well lengthens, two things become evident in board rooms. Existing debts are easily validated and units that were heavily in debt prospered; it paid to lever. After the event it becomes apparent that the margins of safety built into debt structures were too great. As a result, over a period in which the economy does well, views about acceptable debt structure change. In the dealmaking that goes on between banks, investment bankers, and businessmen, the acceptable amount of debt to use in financing various types of activity and positions increases. This increase in the weight of debt financing raises the market price of capital assets and increases investment. As this continues the economy is transformed into a boom economy.

Stable growth is inconsistent with the manner in which investment is determined in an economy in which debt-financed ownership of capital assets exists, and the extent to which such debt financing can be carried is market determined. It follows that the fundamental instability of a capitalist economy is upward. The tendency to transform doing well into a speculative investment boom is the basic instability in a capitalist economy. (Minsky 1982, pp. 66–67)

I modeled this process by extending Goodwin’s cyclical growth model—in which profit-rate-motivated investment and employment-rate-motivated wage demands generated a closed limit cycle in employment and income distribution (Goodwin 1967)—to include debt-financed investment. Goodwin’s model reduced to two coupled differential equations in the employment rate (?) and wages share of output (?), where is a Phillips-curve relation and is an investment function depending on the rate of profit :

I replaced Goodwin’s “starkly schematized” (Goodwin 1967, p. 54) assumption that investment equalled profit at all times with an investment function in which investment exceeded profit at high rates of profit, and was below profit at low rates. An equation to represent debt-financed investment was added—Equation —and profit was redefined as earnings net of interest payments :

This transformed Goodwin’s model into a three-state model of Minsky’s hypothesis, with the extra equation being the dynamics of the private debt to output ratio (see Keen 2013, pp. 236–38 for the derivation):

In (Keen 1995; Keen 2000) I used nonlinear functions for both investment determination and wage setting; here I use linear functions to emphasize that both the cyclical behavior of Goodwin’s model and the debt-induced breakdown in the Minsky model are endemic, rather than being products of the assumed functional forms. In the simulations shown in Figure 13 and Figure 14, the investment and wage change functions are:

Figure 13 shows the fixed cycle in Goodwin’s basic model.

Figure 13: Goodwin’s model with linear behavioral functions simulated in Minsky

Figure 14 shows a typical run of the Minsky model, which has three key characteristics:

  • The initial behavior of the model involves a reduction in the volatility of employment and output—effectively a “Great Moderation”;
  • Workers’ share of output has a secular tendency to fall; and
  • The initial reduction in employment and output volatility gives way to increasing volatility as the debt to output level rises (with the ultimate outcome of a debt-induced collapse in output and employment).

Figure 14: Minsky’s FIH with linear behavioral functions simulated in Minsky

The fact that this simple model generated outcomes that, in a very stylized way, mirror the empirical record of the recent economic past, emphasizes the importance of developing an approach to macroeconomics in which banks and private debt play integral roles. The empirical data, interpreted in the light of the theoretical arguments given here, further emphasizes the importance of paying close policy attention to the hitherto ignored phenomenon of the growth of private debt.

  1. Empirical Data

Fortunately, though mainstream economic theory has ignored the role of private debt, statistical agencies have collected the data. Figure 15 is an imputed series combining actual Federal Reserve quarterly data on household plus non-financial corporate debt since 1952 (and yearly data from 1945 till 1952) with US Census data from 1916–1970, and partial Census data on bank loans from 1834 to 1970 (Census 1949; Census 1975).

Figure 15: US private debt since 1834

The causal role of the change in debt in aggregate demand identified in this paper implies that there should be a strong empirical relationship between change in debt and macroeconomic data such as the unemployment rate—in contrast to the Loanable-Funds-based presumption that “Absent implausibly large differences in marginal spending propensities among the groups … pure redistributions should have no significant macro-economic effects…” (Bernanke 2000, p. 24). This Loanable Funds presumption is strongly rejected by the data. As Figure 16 shows, the correlation of the change in debt times velocity (divided by GDP) with the level of unemployment since 1990 is –0.92.

Figure 16: Change in debt times velocity and US Unemployment (Correlation –0.92)

The first difference of also implies a strong relationship between the change in the change in debt over two time periods and change in unemployment over that period. Setting , the change in aggregate demand between periods t2–t1 and t1–t0 (normalized by dividing by ) is:

Setting , the correlation between equation , which we term the Credit Accelerator (see also Biggs and Mayer 2010; Biggs, et al. 2010), and the annual percentage change in the unemployment rate over the period from 1975 till today is –0.78 (see Figure 17).

Figure 17: Credit acceleration and change in unemployment (Correlation –0.78)

  1. Conclusion

Given that bank lending creates money and repayment of debt destroys it, the change in debt plays an integral role in macroeconomics by dynamically varying the level of aggregate demand. The omission of this factor from mainstream economic models is the reason that these models failed to warn of the dangers of the dramatic buildup in private debt since WWII—and especially since 1993, when the debt-financed recovery from the 1990s recession took the aggregate private debt level past the peak caused by deflation in the 1930s (see Figure 15). It is also the reason why they failed to anticipate the crisis that began in 2007, and instead predicted that, as the OECD put it in June 2007, “the current economic situation is in many ways better than what we have experienced in years… Our central forecast remains indeed quite benign” (OECD 2007). Policy makers relying upon mainstream economists as experts on the functioning of the economy thus not only received no warning about the worst economic crisis since the Great Depression, but were falsely led to expect benign rather than malignant economic conditions.

The erroneous neglect of the dynamics of private debt by the economics profession has therefore resulted in enormous social and economic harm to society. This is the opposite of the intended goal of economic theory and policy. If economic theory and policy are to fulfil their intended role, it is imperative that a reformed macroeconomics be developed in which banks, money and the dynamics of debt play integral roles.

  1. Appendix

    1. Loanable Funds model

Differential equations for money and debt

Other differential equations

  1. Endogenous Money model

Differential equations for money and debt

Other differential equations

Common Definitions

Common Parameters to Loanable Funds and Endogenous Money models

  1. Goodwin model
  1. Minsky model (new and modified equations only)
  1. Common parameters to Goodwin & Minsky models
  1. Minsky

Minsky is an addition to the family of system dynamics programs that began with Jay Forrester’s pioneering work on developing a visual metaphor for constructing and simulating dynamic models of complex social and economic processes (Forrester 1968). Forrester’s metaphor was the flowchart (see Figure 18): a drawing of the relationships in a system became the framework for developing a mathematical model of that system:

The proposed model structure and method of solution retain a one-to-one correspondence between the presumed form of the real economic world and the quantities, coefficients, variables, and decision criteria of the model. Formulation in terms of a “flow diagram” is possible so that a pictorial representation of the relationships within the system is available at all times. (Forrester 2003p. 344 )

Figure 18: The first system dynamics diagram from Forrester 2003 (1956)

There are now at least a dozen programs implementing this modeling philosophy, ranging from the free Open Source program Xcos to the $20,000-a-copy commercial program Simulink. This paradigm is now pervasive in engineering, but it failed to take root in economics, despite the fact that Forrester’s concept was twice anticipated in economics—firstly by Irving Fisher in 1891 with a hydraulic model for calculating equilibrium values in a Walrasian model (Brainard and Scarf), and then by the engineer-turned economist Bill Phillips with genuinely dynamic analog computer systems (Hayes 2011; Leeson 1994a; Leeson 1994b; Leeson 1995; Leeson 2000; Phillips 1950; Phillips 1954; Phillips 1957) some years before Forrester. However, there was no development in economics comparable to Forrester’s innovation (in conjunction with the computer programmers Phyllis Fox and Alexander Pugh–see Lane 2007) of a digital computer program—DYNAMO—to provide a general purpose foundation for building dynamic models of complex systems.

Figure 19: Fisher’s 1891 hydraulic machine for calculating Walrasian equilibrium prices, from Brainard and Scarf, p. 69

Figure 20: Phillips’s schematic diagram of a dynamic multiplier-accelerator model, from Phillips 1954, p. 306

The core paradigm in system dynamics programs is the construction of mathematical equations via flowcharts identical in spirit to that developed by Phillips (see Figure 20). For example, Figure 21 is the system dynamics equivalent of the differential equation for exponential population growth .

Figure 21: A simple algebraic equation in a system dynamics program (Minsky)

Simple expressions like this are just as easily rendered in equations or standard text-oriented computer programs, but the system dynamics approach makes it easier to comprehend much more complex models—hence its dominance in the engineering field today.

Minsky provides this classic system dynamics approach, and also adds a new method of constructing differential equations to the system dynamics toolkit that is superior for modelling financial flows: the Godley Table. Based on the accounting concept of double-entry bookkeeping, each column represents the dynamic equation of a given financial account, while each row represents transactions between accounts. This is a more natural way to portray financial transactions which also helps enforce the fundamental rules of accounting—that Assets equal Liabilities plus Equity.

Minsky ensures this in three ways. Firstly, all row operations in a Godley Table must sum to zero—otherwise an error is flagged. Secondly, the source of any transaction is shown as a positive while the destination (or “sink” in system dynamics parlance) is shown as a negative. Thirdly, Assets are shown as positive while Liabilities and Equity are shown as negative. Figure 22 illustrates these three conventions—including showing what happens when they are breached.

Figure 22: A sample Godley Table

References

Bernanke, Ben S.

    2000    Essays on the Great Depression. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Bezemer, Dirk J

    2009    “No One Saw This Coming”: Understanding Financial Crisis Through Accounting Models. Groningen, The Netherlands: Faculty of Economics University of Groningen.

Biggs, Michael, and Thomas Mayer

    2010    The Output Gap Conundrum. Intereconomics/Review of European Economic Policy 45(1):11–16.

Biggs, Michael, Thomas Mayer, and Andreas Pick

    2010    Credit and Economic Recovery: Demystifying Phoenix Miracles. SSRN eLibrary.

Blanchard, Olivier

    2009    The State of Macro. Annual Review of Economics 1(1):209–228.

Blanchard, Olivier, Giovanni Dell’Ariccia, and Paolo Mauro

    2010    Rethinking Macroeconomic Policy. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 42:199–215.

Brainard, William C., and Herbert E. Scarf

        How to Compute Equilibrium Prices in 1891. American Journal of Economics and Sociology 64:57–83.

Carney, John

    2012    What Really Constrains Bank Lending. In NetNet. J. Carney, ed. New York: CNBC.

Carpenter, Seth B., and Selva Demiralp

    2010    Money, Reserves, and the Transmission of Monetary Policy: Does the Money Multiplier Exist? In Finance and Economics Discussion Series. Washington: Federal Reserve Board.

Census, Bureau of

    1949    Historical Statistics of the United States 1789–1945. B.o.t. Census, ed. Washington: United States Government.

    1975    Historical Statistics of the United States Colonial Times to 1970. B.o.t. Census, ed. Washington: United States Government.

ECB

    2012    Monetary and Financial Developments. In Monthly Bulletin May 2012. Brussels: European Central Bank.

Eggertsson, Gauti B., and Paul Krugman

    2012a    Debt, Deleveraging, and the Liquidity Trap: A Fisher-Minsky-Koo approach. Quarterly Journal of Economics 127:1469–1513.

    2012b    Supplementary material to Debt, Deleveraging and the Liquidity Trap. Quarterly Journal of Economics 127:Appendix.

Einstein, Albert

    1934    On the Method of Theoretical Physics. Philosophy of Science 1:163–169.

Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French

    1999    The Corporate Cost of Capital and the Return on Corporate Investment. Journal of Finance 54(6):1939–1967.

Fisher, Irving

    1933    The Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions. Econometrica 1(4):337–357.

Forrester, Jay W.

    1968    Industrial Dynamics-After the First Decade. Management Science 14(7):398–415.

    2003    Dynamic models of economic systems and industrial organizations: Note to the Faculty research seminar. From Jay W. Forrester. November 5, 1956. System Dynamics Review 19(4):329–45.

Friedman, Milton

    1948    A Monetary and Fiscal Framework for Economic Stability. The American Economic Review 38(3):245–264.

    1959    The Demand for Money: Some Theoretical and Empirical Results. The American Economic Review 49(2):525–527.

    1969    The Optimum Quantity of Money. In The Optimum Quantity of Money and Other Essays. Pp. 1–50. Chicago: MacMillan.

Friedman, Milton, and Anna Jacobson Schwartz

    1963    A monetary history of the United States 1867–1960. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Fullwiler, Scott

    2012    Krugman’s Flashing Neon Sign. In New Economic Perspectives. S. Kelton, ed. Kansas City: Stephanie Kelton.

Goodwin, Richard M.

    1967    A growth cycle. In Socialism, Capitalism and Economic Growth. C.H. Feinstein, ed. Pp. 54–58. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Graziani, Augusto

    1989    The Theory of the Monetary Circuit. Thames Papers in Political Economy Spring:1–26.

Hayes, Brian

    2011    Economics, Control Theory, and the Phillips Machine. ASSRU — Algorithmic Social Science Research Unit.

Holmes, Alan R.

    1969    Operational Constraints on the Stabilization of Money Supply Growth. In Controlling Monetary Aggregates. F.E. Morris, ed. Pp. 65–77. Nantucket Island: The Federal Reserve Bank of Boston.

Keen, Steve

    1995    Finance and Economic Breakdown: Modeling Minsky’s ‘Financial Instability Hypothesis.’. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 17(4):607–635.

    2000    The Nonlinear Economics of Debt Deflation. In Commerce, complexity, and evolution: Topics in economics, finance, marketing, and management: Proceedings of the Twelfth International Symposium in Economic Theory and Econometrics. W.A. Barnett, C. Chiarella, S. Keen, R. Marks, and H. Schnabl, eds. Pp. 83–110. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    2013    Predicting the ‘Global Financial Crisis’: Post-Keynesian Macroeconomics. Economic Record 89(285):228–254.

    2014    Secular stagnation and endogenous money. Real World Economics Review 66:2–11.

Keister, T., and J. McAndrews

    2009    Why Are Banks Holding So Many Excess Reserves? New York: Federal Reserve Bank of New York.

Krugman, Paul

    2012a    Banking Mysticism. In The Conscience of a Liberal. New York: New York Times.

    2012b    Banking Mysticism, Continued. In The Conscience of a Liberal. New York: New York Times.

    2012c    End this Depression Now! New York: W.W. Norton.

    2012d    Minsky and Methodology (Wonkish). In The Conscience of a Liberal. New York: New York Times.

    2012e    Oh My, Steve Keen Edition. In The Conscience of a Liberal. New York: New York Times.

    2012f    Things I Should Not Be Wasting Time On. In The Conscience of a Liberal. New York: New York Times.

    2013a    Commercial Banks As Creators of “Money”. In The Conscience of a Liberal.

    2013b    Secular Stagnation Arithmetic. In The Conscience of a Liberal. P. Krugman, ed. New York: New York Times.

Kydland, Finn E., and Edward C. Prescott

    1990    Business Cycles: Real Facts and a Monetary Myth. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 14(2):3–18.

Lane, David C.

    2007    The power of the bond between cause and effect: Jay Wright Forrester and the field of system dynamics. System Dynamics Review 23:95–118.

Leeson, Robert

    1994a    Some Misunderstandings Concerning the Contributions Made by A. W. H. Phillips and R. G. Lipsey to the Inflation-Unemployment Literature. History of Economics Review (22):70–82.

    1994b    A. W. H. Phillips M.B.E. (Military Division). Economic Journal 104(424):605–618.

    1995    A. W. H. Phillips: His Machine and His Curve. New Zealand Economic Papers 29(2):231–243.

    2000    A. W. H. Phillips: An Extraordinary Life. In A. W. H. Phillips: Collected works in contemporary perspective. R. Leeson, ed. Pp. 3–17. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Minsky, Hyman

    1978    The Financial Instability Hypothesis: A Restatement. Thames Papers in Political Economy Autumn 1978.

Minsky, Hyman P.

    1980    Capitalist Financial Processes and the Instability of Capitalism. Journal of Economic Issues 14(2):505–523.

    1982    Can “it” happen again? : essays on instability and finance. Armonk, N.Y.: M.E. Sharpe.

Moore, Basil J.

    1979    The Endogenous Money Stock. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 2(1):49–70.

    1983    Unpacking the Post Keynesian Black Box: Bank Lending and the Money Supply. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 5(4):537–556.

OECD

    2007    Achieving Further Rebalancing. In OECD Economic Outlook. OECD, ed: OECD Publishing.

Palley, Thomas

    2013    Horizontalists, verticalists, and structuralists: the theory of endogenous money reassessed. Review of Keynesian Economics 1(4):406–424.

Palley, Thomas I.

    1991    The Endogenous Money Supply: Consensus and Disagreement. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 13(3):397–403.

    2002    Endogenous Money: What It Is and Why It Matters. Metroeconomica 53(2):152–180.

Phillips, A. W.

    1950    Mechanical Models in Economic Dynamics. Economica 17(67):283–305.

    1954    Stabilisation Policy in a Closed Economy. The Economic Journal 64(254):290–323.

    1957    Stabilisation Policy and the Time-Forms of Lagged Responses. The Economic Journal 67(266):265–277.

Roche, Cullen

    2013    Keep Banks Out of Macro? In Pragmatic Capitalism. C. Roche, ed. New York: Orcam Financial Group, LLC.

Rowe, Nick

    2013    What Steve Keen is maybe trying to say. In Worthwhile Canadian Initiative. N. Rowe, ed. Canada.

Smets, Frank, and Rafael Wouters

    2007    Shocks and Frictions in US Business Cycles: A Bayesian DSGE Approach. American Economic Review 97(3):586–606.

Solow, Robert M.

    2003    Dumb and Dumber in Macroeconomics. In Festschrift for Joe Stiglitz. Columbia University.

    2008    The State of Macroeconomics. The Journal of Economic Perspectives 22(1):243–246.

Sumner, Scott

    2013    Keep banks out of macro. In The Money Illusion. Bentley: Scott Sumner.

Tobin, J.

    1963    Commercial banks as creators of “money”. In Banking and Monetary Studies. D. Carson, ed. Pp. 408–419. Washington: Comptroller of the Currency.

Woodford, Michael

    2009    Convergence in Macroeconomics: Elements of the New Synthesis. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 1(1):267–79.

 

 


Source: http://www.debtdeflation.com/blogs/2014/02/02/modeling-financial-instability/#utm_source=feed&utm_medium=feed&utm_campaign=feed


Before It’s News® is a community of individuals who report on what’s going on around them, from all around the world.

Anyone can join.
Anyone can contribute.
Anyone can become informed about their world.

"United We Stand" Click Here To Create Your Personal Citizen Journalist Account Today, Be Sure To Invite Your Friends.

Please Help Support BeforeitsNews by trying our Natural Health Products below!


Order by Phone at 888-809-8385 or online at https://mitocopper.com M - F 9am to 5pm EST

Order by Phone at 866-388-7003 or online at https://www.herbanomic.com M - F 9am to 5pm EST

Order by Phone at 866-388-7003 or online at https://www.herbanomics.com M - F 9am to 5pm EST


Humic & Fulvic Trace Minerals Complex - Nature's most important supplement! Vivid Dreams again!

HNEX HydroNano EXtracellular Water - Improve immune system health and reduce inflammation.

Ultimate Clinical Potency Curcumin - Natural pain relief, reduce inflammation and so much more.

MitoCopper - Bioavailable Copper destroys pathogens and gives you more energy. (See Blood Video)

Oxy Powder - Natural Colon Cleanser!  Cleans out toxic buildup with oxygen!

Nascent Iodine - Promotes detoxification, mental focus and thyroid health.

Smart Meter Cover -  Reduces Smart Meter radiation by 96%! (See Video).

Report abuse

    Comments

    Your Comments
    Question   Razz  Sad   Evil  Exclaim  Smile  Redface  Biggrin  Surprised  Eek   Confused   Cool  LOL   Mad   Twisted  Rolleyes   Wink  Idea  Arrow  Neutral  Cry   Mr. Green

    MOST RECENT
    Load more ...

    SignUp

    Login

    Newsletter

    Email this story
    Email this story

    If you really want to ban this commenter, please write down the reason:

    If you really want to disable all recommended stories, click on OK button. After that, you will be redirect to your options page.